Hi all,
The book on t-shirts I mentioned: http://www.amazon.com/The-Travels-T-Shirt-Global-Economy/dp/0471648493
HIST610.15
Tuesday, December 1, 2015
Empire of Cotton: Prompt question #3 Response
Answer to question 3:
I took this question to be one about raw cotton rather than
cotton products. Raw cotton itself did
not have much economic value in the 16th century in Europe, but
cotton products had tremendous value. In
fact, raw cotton didn’t even have much value up through the 17th and
18th centuries, either. Beckert
writes, “The modest demand for raw cotton
among European manufacturers of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries,
before they heyday of the new machines that would by 1780 revolutionize cotton
manufacturing, was largely met through established and diversified trade
channels.” (40). Raw cotton was in only “modest” demand because manufacturers
of cotton could not compete with Asian manufacturers, in large part, as Beckert
argues, because of wage costs. While raw
cotton was in modest demands during the seventeenth and eighteenth century, it
seems that the same was true for the 16th century as well. Cotton industry had begun to sprout in
northern Italy and southern Germany, but at this time “within Europe, the
industry was not yet particularly prominent.
Europeans still largely dressed in linen and woolens, not cottons” (27). Later, while Great Britain had begun to
establish its dominance throughout the global markets through what Beckert
describes as “war capitalism,” Indian cotton products were still of a higher
quality and cheaper than British cotton products. It was not until manufacturing took off at
the end of the 17th century that Britain was able to compete with
Indian products by drastically reducing the hours needed to spin cotton. War capitalism had been able to both,
ironically, make trading in Indian products profitable by dominating global
markets and protecting domestic cotton products at home. However, it was only when, in 1790, British
manufacturing gained the ability to spin a hundred pounds of raw cotton in just
1,000 hours (compared to the 50,000 hours it took Indian workers, 66) that
cotton itself began to have real value in Europe. Even beyond the economic value of the
increase in the rate of productivity, industrial capitalism was a revolution in
that “workers were neither enslaved nor populations murdered,” (79) making war
capitalism irrelevant in the progression of what “Hegel would call the ‘spirit
of history’” (79).
Monday, November 30, 2015
Empire of Cotton Response
In Empire of Cotton author
Sven Beckert lays out a new definition for the economics system which governed
the globalization of the cotton industry. Previously referred too mercantilism
Beckart calls this system “war capitalism.” The provocative name is used to describe
an economic system based on state coercion, imperialism, slavery, wage
deflation and “armed trade.” He coins this phrase for a number of reasons,
perhaps chiefly to push the genesis of western capitalistic enterprise back
from 1780 to the 16th century. Beckert’s definition of capitalism is
very different than the classical definition exposed by economists. For Beckert
“war capitalism” and by extension capitalism generally is dependent upon the
state for protectionist tariffs, the seizure of land, etc. Industrial
capitalism is simply the mechanization of the cotton reefing process. The use
of environmental power such as falling water and eventually steam allow British
textile producers to compensate for their high labor costs and to double down
on ealier market gains. Rather than overturn “war capitalism,” this new
mechanized Industrial capitalism for Beckert served to buttress it by pairing
the coercive power of the state with an unmatched technical edge. These gains
along with capital and overseas territorial possessions allowed British
producers to dominate world cotton markets.
Empire of Cotton post
Empire of Cotton
offers a detailed account of capitalism in the 19th century by using
a single commodity as a lens for examining this. There were many similar
aspects of this particular history to Cronin’s Changes in the Land lying in their discussions of European
expansion, land (environment, exhaustion of natural resources), exploitation of
the indigenous peoples, and more. In our class discussions regarding Cronin’s
book, it was decided that he was actually talking about a capitalist market in
New England and utilizing the environment surrounding in which it was situated
in as a lens in which to examine this. Beckert’s book is much more direct and
expansive providing a global look at how this commodity had so much power. He
shows the process of this to be violent not only in the American South Pre/Post
Civil War, but also in how it had a role in the destruction of local economies
in Asia and the Middle East.
The book seems to be broken up into two separate sections as
he used the production of cotton as a lens for the development of the modern
world. The first “war capitalism” is used to illustrate how the colonial
conquest and slavery prepared the ground for the cotton industry. He also uses “industrial
capitalism” to discuss how states intervened to protect and help the industry
along. I think that this history offers excellent insight into how influential
a commodity can be not just locally, but globally, but I found that I had
difficulty believing his argument that it was this specific commodity that kick-started
the industrial revolution because there’s never just one spark that lights the
fire for change to take place on such a large level.
King Cotton's harsh reign
Cotton, perhaps the premier commodity in a world of many commodities, became an important item for so many people around the world and helped fuel the widening gap between a few wealthier countries and their people and many more poorer countries and poorer people, which is also known as the Great Divergence.
The winners were the wealthier people of Europe and their cultural descendants around the world, but not, according to Beckert, for the reasons many economists and historians have previously claimed. For example, some have argued “that Europe’s explosive economic development can be explained by Europeans’ more rational religious beliefs, their Enlightenment traditions, the climate in which they live, the continent’s geography, or benign institutions such as the Bank of England or the rule of law” (Kindle Locations 147-155). Rather, Europeans basically kicked the crap out of the world, bending the will and breaking the backs of others through unfair, if not inhumane, methods of domination.
Europe and, eventually, the United States protected their markets, used government finances and financial policy, and subdued and enslaved people around the world to wring efficiencies and maximize profits, as capitalism and cotton were global forces. The harsh, unfree, unfair, and state-controlled approach to making cotton profitable is referred to by Beckert as “war capitalism” and is an important precursor to, and enabler of, industrial capitalism and the Industrial Revolution. According to Beckert, “Such a thorough and rapid re-creation of the world was possible only because of the emergence of new ways of organizing production, trade, and consumption. Slavery, the expropriation of indigenous peoples, imperial expansion, armed trade, and the assertion of sovereignty over people and land by entrepreneurs were at its core. I call this system war capitalism” (Kindle Locations 175-182). Beckert points out that the sixteenth century ushered in war capitalism and the more important beginning of the trends that led to the Great Divergence, rather than the 1800s beginning of the Industrial Revolution.
The western world might be close to experiencing a harsh dose of karma as Asia is using somewhat more subtle methods to become a more powerful player in the worlds cotton and global capitalism. State control and direction may yet again prove to be a more powerful determinant in financial success than freer markets and the invisible hand.
I loved this book. It was interesting, informative, and thought-provoking. The one issue I felt was left unresolved was why Europe utilized war capitalism on other parts of the world, and not the other way around. What allowed or compelled Europe to push forward first? I felt a chicken and egg issue was still left unresolved here. For me, Jared Diamond’s Guns, Germs, and Steel offered more closure on “why Europe?” I’m not sure he’s right, but he offers a more thorough answer. Still, Beckert thoroughly explains a certain phase in the Great Divergence and has me thinking about this topic so much more than I ever did before.
Empire of Cotton
Sven Beckert's Empire of Cotton, is what I believe to be a continuation of the modern historical trend of focusing on one topic and somehow making it sound like that topic was the most important event in the history of the world. Other books in this idea are COD: A Biography of the Fish that Changed the World Book by Mark Kurlansky or How the Irish Saved Civilization book by Thomas Cahill. While Beckert's book is extremely detailed and well written, I do though find large claims like these a bit hard to grasp. Beckert's war capitalism for the rise of cotton notion is, while a driving force, was not the only piece to this puzzle of the rise of Colonialism and Worldwide political and economic dominance. There was a need for land for rapidly growing populations, new markets that opened up once the Ottoman Empires grasp on the seas was weaken when their drive into Europe was stopped at the doors of Vienna.
Sven's work though does direct ones attention to a topic that most people would just glance over and not give a second thought. I found myself rapidly reading his work and doing side research to expand my personal understanding of this topic. Maybe this is the point of single focus historical books now, to seek out and find those silences, need it be a group of people or a plant by-product that was easy to spin and dye. I know that I couldnt put this work down until it was all done.
Sven's work though does direct ones attention to a topic that most people would just glance over and not give a second thought. I found myself rapidly reading his work and doing side research to expand my personal understanding of this topic. Maybe this is the point of single focus historical books now, to seek out and find those silences, need it be a group of people or a plant by-product that was easy to spin and dye. I know that I couldnt put this work down until it was all done.
Cotton, War Capitalism, (and Gender?)
In Empire of
Cotton, Beckert leads us on a journey through the framework and evolution
of capitalism through the lens of cotton. In what he describes as “war
capitalism”, he details the foundations of global markets and global power
relations as they developed around the cotton market and all it affected (which
in scope was nearly all aspects of global relations spanning the past several
hundred years).
Beckert’s work seemingly plays on the current
historical interest in the history of capitalism. Throughout the course we have
moved further away from social history as founded by Bloch/Braudel and more towards
other facets of history, a big one being economic history. Several historians
have criticized Beckert’s inconsistencies and contrary reductionism found in
his understanding of mercantilism, aka “war capitalism” in the 17th,
18th, and 19th centuries. Despite this fact, his work
brings out many facets of a common commodity that’s history can be understood
as a parallel to European imperialism, foreign relations, and globalism.
“The empire of cotton was, from the beginning, a site of constant global struggle between slaves and planters, merchants and statesmen, farmers and merchants, workers and factory owners. In this as in so many other ways, the empire of cotton ushered in the modern world.” (Sadly I have this on an old kindle and thus won’t have any exact page relations for my citations. This one is 178-87 on my version) When it comes to such power relations, highly gendered I might add, Berkert goes in much detail as to how the Europeans came to control the cotton market. The European dominance was not a result of their inherent militaristic or political supremacy, but rather a side effect of their capitalistic and economic interests. “This recasting of cotton did not at first derive from technological advantages, but instead from a far simpler source: the ability and willingness to project capital and power across vast oceans. With increasing frequency, Europeans inserted themselves, often violently, into the global networks of the cotton trade…before using that same power to create entirely novel networks between Africa, the Americas, and Europe…Europeans became important to the worlds of cotton not because of their ability to reshape and then dominate global cotton networks.” The Europeans would accumulate interest of the industry, integrate themselves into it, often imperialistically and militaristically, internalize the processes, and then reap the source, often utilizing systems of protectionism that would ensure their economic dominance.
“The empire of cotton was, from the beginning, a site of constant global struggle between slaves and planters, merchants and statesmen, farmers and merchants, workers and factory owners. In this as in so many other ways, the empire of cotton ushered in the modern world.” (Sadly I have this on an old kindle and thus won’t have any exact page relations for my citations. This one is 178-87 on my version) When it comes to such power relations, highly gendered I might add, Berkert goes in much detail as to how the Europeans came to control the cotton market. The European dominance was not a result of their inherent militaristic or political supremacy, but rather a side effect of their capitalistic and economic interests. “This recasting of cotton did not at first derive from technological advantages, but instead from a far simpler source: the ability and willingness to project capital and power across vast oceans. With increasing frequency, Europeans inserted themselves, often violently, into the global networks of the cotton trade…before using that same power to create entirely novel networks between Africa, the Americas, and Europe…Europeans became important to the worlds of cotton not because of their ability to reshape and then dominate global cotton networks.” The Europeans would accumulate interest of the industry, integrate themselves into it, often imperialistically and militaristically, internalize the processes, and then reap the source, often utilizing systems of protectionism that would ensure their economic dominance.
In an essence, without delving into the full range
of Beckert’s intricacies, the cotton industry as a prime mover of modern
capitalism led the West into the Industrial Revolution and setting the stage
for modern power relations. Reading the first part of his work, I couldn’t help
but notice two things. First, the parallels, and to some extent the
differences, between our modern outsourced capitalism and the 16th
and 17th centuries. One that balances on outsourcing the labor to
cut costs, just as the Europeans did upon domination of the cotton industry,
coupled with certain notions of protectionism. Though I am not an economic
specialist, as I understand it our modern institutions of protectionism are not
as direct as such early forms of capitalism, yet the basic concepts are still
the same. Make others do the work, for as little as possible, and reap the
benefits especially when brought back into our own markets. Secondly, although
Berkert alludes to the topic on occasion, the gendered notions that are imbued
upon capitalism and its formation. As Joan Scott mentions, gender is the root
binary, and Catharine Hall/Leonore Davidoff
discuss in Family of Fortune, class
and gender are inseparably linked. Even greater than such a notion, gender
defines relations between nations, races, negotiations and economies, and even industry
itself. Focus on capitalism and gender spurred around the early 1990’s followed
by economic and commodity histories. Beckert’s work here is the latest
iteration of such ideology and helps us better understand the large from the
small. Though in this case, perhaps it’s better understood as the largess of
the seemingly inconsequential.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)